In defense of globalisation-Nike and Vietnam - Page 2 - Politics Forum.org | PoFo

Wandering the information superhighway, he came upon the last refuge of civilization, PoFo, the only forum on the internet ...

"It's the economy, stupid!"

Moderator: PoFo Economics & Capitalism Mods

Forum rules: No one line posts please.
By Freedom
#23845
To be honest Catria i have no real problems with Trade Unions asking for increase standards for work places and ensuring their rights. But in poor countries like thos mentioned above, pushing a minimum wage to European standards say, would just make a whole lot of homeless people in those countries. Look at Germany they run a huge Welfare state they are running 4million unemployed and one of the slowest rates of growth in the world. Better working conditions are okay, but raising a minimum wage would have the effect of creating more poverty than solving it.

Speaking of the Industrial Revolution...is it not true that it raised the standard of living of the people and slashed Child mortality rates and raised the life expectancy? Isnt this what will happen in those countries?
By Catria
#23934
Speaking of the Industrial Revolution...is it not true that it raised the standard of living of the people and slashed Child mortality rates and raised the life expectancy? Isnt this what will happen in those countries?


Hopefully, but as with the industrial revolution, fair labour standards will have to be wrung from the capitalists through blood, sweat and tears....it wont offer them willingly.
By CasX
#24126
Exactly. T'was from this capitalist nightmare that Trade Unions were born.

And good god, we owe them for the struggle they undertook.

Or should I say, undertake...
By Freedom
#26192
On how capitalism perpetuates inequality...sorta...

How Globalization Conquers Poverty
By Johan Norberg

In 1870, Sweden was poorer than Congo is today. People lived twenty years shorter than they do in developing countries today, and infant mortality was twice as high as in the average developing country. My forefathers were literally starving.

But reforms for liberalization at home and free trade abroad changed all of this. A trade agreement with England and France in 1865 made it possible for Swedes to specialize. We couldn’t produce food well, but we could produce steel and timber, and sell it abroad. For the money we made, we could buy food.

In 1870, the industrial revolution began in Sweden. New companies exported to countries across the world, and production grew rapidly. The competition forced our companies to become more efficient, and old industries were closed so that we could meet new demands, such as better clothes, sanitation, health care and education.

By 1950 — when the Swedish welfare state was no more than a glint in the social democrat’s eye — the Swedish economy had quadrupled. Infant mortality had been reduced by 85 per cent and life expectancy had increased by a miraculous 25 years. We were on our way to abolishing poverty. We had globalized.

Even more interesting is that Sweden grew at a much faster rate than the developed countries it traded with. The wages in Sweden grew from 33 per cent of the average wage in the US in 1870 to 56 per cent in the early 1900s, even though American wages soared at the same time.

This shouldn’t surprise anyone. Economic models predict that poor countries should have higher growth rates than affluent ones. They have more latent resources to harness, and they can benefit from the existence of wealthier nations to which they export goods and from which they import capital and more advanced technology, whereas affluent countries have already captured many of those gains.

It’s a clear-cut case. Except for one small problem. This relationship does not exist.

Most poor countries grow more slowly than the industrialized countries. The reason is simple: most developing countries cannot make use of these international opportunities. And the two most significant reasons for this are man-made: domestic and external obstacles. Domestic barriers such as a lack of the rule of law, a stable climate for investment, and the protection of property rights. External barriers such as rich country protectionism in goods of particular importance to the third world — textiles and agriculture — that (according to UNCTAD) deprives developing countries of nearly $700 billion in export income a year – almost 14 times more than they receive in foreign aid.

But when we look at the poor countries with good institutions, and which are open to trade, we see that they are making rapid progress, much faster than the wealthy countries. A classic study by Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner of 117 countries in the 1970s and 1980s showed that open-developing countries had an annual growth rate of 4.5 percent, compared with 0.7 per cent in closed-developing countries and 2.3 percent in open industrialized countries. A recent World Bank report concluded that 24 developing countries with a total population of 3 billion are integrating into the global economy more quickly than ever. Their growth per capita has also increased from 1 per cent in the 1960s to 5 per cent in the 1990s (compared to a rich country growth of 1.9 per cent). At the present rate, the average citizen in these developing countries will see her income doubled in less than 15 years.

This points to the conclusion that globalization, the increase in international trade, communications and investments, is the most efficient means in history of extending international opportunity. The anti-globalists are correct when they claim that large parts of the world are left out, especially Sub-Saharan Africa. But that also happens to be the least liberal part of the world, with the most controls and regulations, and the weakest tradition of property rights. When anti-globalists blame globalization for African misery, it rings just as bizarre as the North Korean officials who once explained to a visiting Mongolian politician that the average North Korean is unhappy and miserable because he is sad about American imperialism.

On the whole, official statistics from governments, the UN and the World Bank all point in the direction that mankind has never before seen such a dramatic improvement of the human condition as we’ve seen in the last three decades. We have heard the opposite view repeated so many times, that we take it for granted, without examining the evidence.

During the last 30 years, chronic hunger and the extent of child labour in the developing countries have been cut in half. In the last half century, life expectancy has gone up from 46 to 64 years and infant mortality has been reduced from 18 to 8 per cent. These indicators are much better in the developing world today than they were in the richest countries a hundred years ago.

In a generation, the average income in developing countries has doubled. As the United Nations Development Programme has observed, in the last 50 years global poverty has declined more than in the 500 years before that. The number of absolute poor — people with less than $1/day — has according to the World Bank been reduced by 200 million in the last two decades, even though world population grew by about 1.5 billion during the same time.

Even those encouraging findings, however, probably overestimate world poverty, because the World Bank uses survey data as the basis for its assessments. This data is notoriously unreliable. It suggests that South Korean is richer than the Swedes and British, for example, and that Ethiopia is richer than India.

Furthermore, surveys capture less and less of an individual’s income. The average poor person at exactly the same level of poverty in surveys in 1987 and 1998 had in reality seen her income increase by 17 per cent. Former World Bank economist Surjit S Bhalla recently published his own calculations supplementing survey results with national accounts data (in the book Imagine There’s No Country, Institute for International Economics, 2002). Bhalla found that UN’s goal of lowering world poverty to below 15 percent by 2015 has already been achieved and surpassed. Absolute poverty had actually fallen from a level of 44 percent in 1980 to 13 percent in 2000.

Bhalla also shows that the GDP per capita of the developing countries taken as a whole (not as individual countries) grew by 3.1 percent 1980-2000, compared to the industrialized world’s 1.6 percent. These countries are now repeating the Swedish experience from the late 19th century, only faster. From 1780, it took England almost 60 years to double its wealth. A hundred years later, Sweden did it in about 40 years, and another century later it took South Korea just a bit more than 10 years.

The world has never been a better place to live in than it is today. Poverty has never been this low, and living standards so high. And the era of globalization has created the setting for an even faster growth of opportunities and wealth creation.

Hold on to your hat.


Here is a link to a debate by the author of this article and author of "Indefence of Globalisation" in which the original article on Vietnam was taken whose website can be seen at http://www.timbro.com/ and Fair Trade thinker Robert Kuttner(note, commies may not like some of the reference to marxism but anyway) who has a website http://www.prospect.org/ . The debate can be seen here http://www.cato.org/special/symposium/debate.html its interest. The debate is hosted on Libertarian think http://www.cato.org and is sponsered by http://www.thenation.com and http://www.aworldconnected.org and the above links also ie CATO, Timbro and Prospect.

Click here: http://www.cato.org/special/symposium/index.html to find articles and websites on both Pro and Anti Free Trade websites, essays and think tanks.

Its pretty interesting. I hope you enjoy it!
By Gothmog
#26261
Freedom wrote:On how capitalism perpetuates inequality...sorta...

How Globalization Conquers Poverty
By Johan Norberg

In 1870, Sweden was poorer than Congo is today. People lived twenty years shorter than they do in developing countries today, and infant mortality was twice as high as in the average developing country. My forefathers were literally starving.

But reforms for liberalization at home and free trade abroad changed all of this. A trade agreement with England and France in 1865 made it possible for Swedes to specialize. We couldn’t produce food well, but we could produce steel and timber, and sell it abroad. For the money we made, we could buy food.

In 1870, the industrial revolution began in Sweden. New companies exported to countries across the world, and production grew rapidly. The competition forced our companies to become more efficient, and old industries were closed so that we could meet new demands, such as better clothes, sanitation, health care and education.

By 1950 — when the Swedish welfare state was no more than a glint in the social democrat’s eye — the Swedish economy had quadrupled. Infant mortality had been reduced by 85 per cent and life expectancy had increased by a miraculous 25 years. We were on our way to abolishing poverty. We had globalized.

Even more interesting is that Sweden grew at a much faster rate than the developed countries it traded with. The wages in Sweden grew from 33 per cent of the average wage in the US in 1870 to 56 per cent in the early 1900s, even though American wages soared at the same time.

This shouldn’t surprise anyone. Economic models predict that poor countries should have higher growth rates than affluent ones. They have more latent resources to harness, and they can benefit from the existence of wealthier nations to which they export goods and from which they import capital and more advanced technology, whereas affluent countries have already captured many of those gains.

It’s a clear-cut case. Except for one small problem. This relationship does not exist.

Most poor countries grow more slowly than the industrialized countries. The reason is simple: most developing countries cannot make use of these international opportunities. And the two most significant reasons for this are man-made: domestic and external obstacles. Domestic barriers such as a lack of the rule of law, a stable climate for investment, and the protection of property rights. External barriers such as rich country protectionism in goods of particular importance to the third world — textiles and agriculture — that (according to UNCTAD) deprives developing countries of nearly $700 billion in export income a year – almost 14 times more than they receive in foreign aid.

But when we look at the poor countries with good institutions, and which are open to trade, we see that they are making rapid progress, much faster than the wealthy countries. A classic study by Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner of 117 countries in the 1970s and 1980s showed that open-developing countries had an annual growth rate of 4.5 percent, compared with 0.7 per cent in closed-developing countries and 2.3 percent in open industrialized countries. A recent World Bank report concluded that 24 developing countries with a total population of 3 billion are integrating into the global economy more quickly than ever. Their growth per capita has also increased from 1 per cent in the 1960s to 5 per cent in the 1990s (compared to a rich country growth of 1.9 per cent). At the present rate, the average citizen in these developing countries will see her income doubled in less than 15 years.

This points to the conclusion that globalization, the increase in international trade, communications and investments, is the most efficient means in history of extending international opportunity. The anti-globalists are correct when they claim that large parts of the world are left out, especially Sub-Saharan Africa. But that also happens to be the least liberal part of the world, with the most controls and regulations, and the weakest tradition of property rights. When anti-globalists blame globalization for African misery, it rings just as bizarre as the North Korean officials who once explained to a visiting Mongolian politician that the average North Korean is unhappy and miserable because he is sad about American imperialism.

On the whole, official statistics from governments, the UN and the World Bank all point in the direction that mankind has never before seen such a dramatic improvement of the human condition as we’ve seen in the last three decades. We have heard the opposite view repeated so many times, that we take it for granted, without examining the evidence.

During the last 30 years, chronic hunger and the extent of child labour in the developing countries have been cut in half. In the last half century, life expectancy has gone up from 46 to 64 years and infant mortality has been reduced from 18 to 8 per cent. These indicators are much better in the developing world today than they were in the richest countries a hundred years ago.

In a generation, the average income in developing countries has doubled. As the United Nations Development Programme has observed, in the last 50 years global poverty has declined more than in the 500 years before that. The number of absolute poor — people with less than $1/day — has according to the World Bank been reduced by 200 million in the last two decades, even though world population grew by about 1.5 billion during the same time.

Even those encouraging findings, however, probably overestimate world poverty, because the World Bank uses survey data as the basis for its assessments. This data is notoriously unreliable. It suggests that South Korean is richer than the Swedes and British, for example, and that Ethiopia is richer than India.

Furthermore, surveys capture less and less of an individual’s income. The average poor person at exactly the same level of poverty in surveys in 1987 and 1998 had in reality seen her income increase by 17 per cent. Former World Bank economist Surjit S Bhalla recently published his own calculations supplementing survey results with national accounts data (in the book Imagine There’s No Country, Institute for International Economics, 2002). Bhalla found that UN’s goal of lowering world poverty to below 15 percent by 2015 has already been achieved and surpassed. Absolute poverty had actually fallen from a level of 44 percent in 1980 to 13 percent in 2000.

Bhalla also shows that the GDP per capita of the developing countries taken as a whole (not as individual countries) grew by 3.1 percent 1980-2000, compared to the industrialized world’s 1.6 percent. These countries are now repeating the Swedish experience from the late 19th century, only faster. From 1780, it took England almost 60 years to double its wealth. A hundred years later, Sweden did it in about 40 years, and another century later it took South Korea just a bit more than 10 years.

The world has never been a better place to live in than it is today. Poverty has never been this low, and living standards so high. And the era of globalization has created the setting for an even faster growth of opportunities and wealth creation.

Hold on to your hat.


-Complete bullshit. Pathetic, laughable....Sweden was not like Congo by 1870. It was poor compared with industrialized country, but was much better than Africa. As the very article say, Sweden was producing steel by 1870´s. And I doubt if they lived 20 years. Even pre industrial societes had life expectancies of around 30-35 years. And the social democrats took power in early 30´s, so their welfare state was already relatively advanced by 1950. Data on economic growth of developing countries is wrong, because they use raw growth rates instead of per capita growth rates. Go to Maddison and see that per capita growth rates for developing countries are actually worse for developing countries since 1973. And globalization in the 90´s didn´t increase overall growth rates of the world economy as a whole. Actually the highest growth rates ever seen happened in the 1950-73 period. Look at the history of 20th century and you will see that the countries who had highest growth rates were those who followed merchantilist policies, as opposed to those who believed in the illusions of free trade or autarky. However, for obvious reasons, merchantilism isn´t a good global strategy, since international trade is a zero sum game (the sum of trade balances of all countries is always zero, so, for each South Korea you will have one or more Guatemala).
Btw: I don´t know the numbers, but it is very possible the the highest growth rates for Sweden happened from 1929-50 and 1950-73, when international trade was on a retraction period. I will examine that data
By Gothmog
#26263
More on Sweden-The author is an idiot. Sweden was already one of the richest countries in the world by 1870. Comparisons with Congo are bullshit. And the highest growth rates happened under Social democrats. It is probably that the performance of SD´s would be even better if 1913-29 and 1929-50 were taken in separate. I suggest you to check your souces better. There are good right wing sites in the Internet, but this one is pathetic. Increase in growth rates from 1870-1900 is probably more related to industrialization than to some abstratct "globalization"


http://www.nationmaster.com/country/sw/Economy


GDP per capita in 1820: $1198 [9th of 24]
GDP per capita in 1900: $2561 [14th of 40]
GDP per capita in 1950: $6738 [8th of 52]
GDP per capita in 1973: $13494 [4th of 52]
GDP (PPP): $215.3 billion [31st of 161]
GDP - real growth rate: 1.8% (2002 est.) [137th of 202]

http://www.eco.rug.nl/~Maddison/Monitor ... apter1.pdf

Here is Maddison on Sweden-GDP by 1990 constant dollars


1820-1198 (near average for Western Europe)
1870-1664 (near average for WE)
1900-2651 (near average for WE)
1913-3096 (near average for WE)
1950-6378 (above average for WE)
1973-13444 (above average for WE)

Annual growth rates
1820-1870: 0,6%
1870-1900: 1,5%
1900-1913: 1,1%
1913-1950: 1,9%
1950-1973: 3,2%
By Freedom
#26336
Afelon for some reason i have respect for you, please dont reply to my posts with "ignorant and pathetic" as the essential point of your argument, it makes you look stupid and pathetic.

According to your sources, in 1870 Sweden had a GDP of 1000+. Which is fine.

In 2002 Congos GDP was 900$

source: http://www.odci.gov/cia/publications/fa ... os/cf.html

Sorry i cant reply with something more substantive but i have to cut back on my internet hours for various reason...i do however plan to answer this properly when i get the time.

Economic Liberty and GDP
-------------

The ten freest countries and their respective GDPS
------
1)Hong Kong---->$24,646.29
2)Singapore---->$23,872.99
3)Luxembourg---->$44,586.23
4)New Zealand--->$19,293.56
5)Ireland---->$28,662.22
6)Denmark---->$28,963.37
7)Estonia---->$10,736.89
8)USA---->$35,935.02
9)Australia---->$27,012.09
10)United Kingdom--->$25,427.41

The least free countries in the world and their respective GDPs

90)Cape Verde--->$1,467.85
91)Gabon--->$5,432.36
92)Croatia--->$8,859.53
93)Guyana--->$3,580.59
94)Moldova--->$2,480.52
95)Algeria--->$5,483.63
96)Lebanon--->$5,111.78
97)Macedonia--->$4,866.65
98)Mozambique--->$892.52
99)Burkina Faso--->$1,015.62
100)Dijbouti---->$1,239.4

The list availible here http://www.nationmaster.com/graph-T/eco_eco_fre and here http://cf.heritage.org/index/pastScores.cfm

more to come
By Gothmog
#26384
Freedom wrote:Afelon for some reason i have respect for you, please dont reply to my posts with "ignorant and pathetic" as the essential point of your argument, it makes you look stupid and pathetic.


-Sorry if you felt offended. I am talking about the author of the text, not about you. Please read my reply again to avoid any misinterpretation. I keep my point that this text is very weak and extremely biased.


According to your sources, in 1870 Sweden had a GDP of 1000+. Which is fine.

In 2002 Congos GDP was 900$



-Right, but in 1870, US$1000 was a quite reasonable GDP while in 2002 it is a miserable one. By 1870, Sweden wasn´t not far from the most developed countries in the world, while Congo, with current levels of development, has not any chance of competing with developed countries, so it´s absurd to compare both societies.



Economic Liberty and GDP
-------------

The ten freest countries and their respective GDPS
------
1)Hong Kong---->$24,646.29
2)Singapore---->$23,872.99
3)Luxembourg---->$44,586.23
4)New Zealand--->$19,293.56
5)Ireland---->$28,662.22
6)Denmark---->$28,963.37
7)Estonia---->$10,736.89
8)USA---->$35,935.02
9)Australia---->$27,012.09
10)United Kingdom--->$25,427.41

The least free countries in the world and their respective GDPs

90)Cape Verde--->$1,467.85
91)Gabon--->$5,432.36
92)Croatia--->$8,859.53
93)Guyana--->$3,580.59
94)Moldova--->$2,480.52
95)Algeria--->$5,483.63
96)Lebanon--->$5,111.78
97)Macedonia--->$4,866.65
98)Mozambique--->$892.52
99)Burkina Faso--->$1,015.62
100)Dijbouti---->$1,239.4

The list availible here http://www.nationmaster.com/graph-T/eco_eco_fre and here http://cf.heritage.org/index/pastScores.cfm

more to come


-I know very well this index, however, the methodology of the Heritage foundation is deeply biased, because it consider some measures of poor economic performance (like inflation) as measures of freedom, which is largely incorret. Furthermore, as you can see, the poverty of the low income countries have roots that are much older than the current period where economic freedom is measured. Mozambique is not poor due to lack of economic freedom, it is poor due to its long past of colonialism and civil war. On the other hand, many of those free countries are former colonial powers which increased their GDP in the 1800´s at the expenses of exploited people (UK comes to my mind).
The best system to measure the effects of freedom would be to evaluate the evolution of economic freedom coupled with with evolution of economic growth, but the Heritage foundation is not interested in doing good research, only in obtaining data which proves their point that freedom makes countries rich. The methodology is so biased that Brazil had almost no change in economic freedom indexes in the last years, despite extensive privatization and opening to foreign investment.
-Btw: Your list is incomplete. China is 125th in the list and still have very high growth rates. It already was doing relatively well before.
By Freedom
#26390
There is another study too, coming to similar findings...i'll try and find it for later.

As for Colonialism...well this isnt exactly true...Ireland had a history of Colonial powers up until the 1920's, yet we rank in the top ten freest countries with good living standards and wages. The real reason is crappy leaders. And crappy leaders lead to civil wars.

Also Mozambique was/is a communist country no?
By Gothmog
#26394
Freedom wrote:As for Colonialism...well this isnt exactly true...Ireland had a history of Colonial powers up until the 1920's, yet we rank in the top ten freest countries with good living standards and wages. The real reason is crappy leaders. And crappy leaders lead to civil wars.


-There is no comparison between the extent of exploitation in Ireland, at least, after 1840´s and in Africa and India. India had 86% of iliiteracy by 1948 and Congo had only 6 people with higher education in the entire country. Non white people were always treated with much more brutality. By 1920, Ireland was in much better shape than any African country.

Also Mozambique was/is a communist country no?


-Yes, a communist country who sufffered from economic sabotage and US sponsored banditism since the very day of its independence, not to mention the military incursions by South Africa. Communist leaders of Mozambique were, btw, reasonably competent for African standards. They won the free elections and are still running the countries. However, according to orthodox marxism, communism isn´t to be developed in colonial countries, it is impossible. Communism can only come from capitalism, so Mozambique´s failure proves that Marx is right.

-Btw2: It seems there is no relation between growth rates and economic freedom, look to the data on per capita GDP growth from 1990-2001. Most top performers were non free countries.

1-Vietnam: 139th on freedom: 4th in economic growth
2-China: 129th on freedom: 2nd in economic growth
3-Hong Kong: 1st on freedom: 65th in economic growth
4-Syria: 146th on freedom: 40th in economic growth
5-Brazil: 73th on freedom: 86th in economic growth
6-Singapore: 2nd on freedom: 11th in economic growth
7-New Zealand: 4th on freedom: 74th in economic growth
8-Chile: 17th on freedom: 7th in economic growth
9-UK: 9th in freedom: 58th in economic growth
10-Finland: 11th in freedom: 50th in economic growth
11-Ireland: 5th in freedom: 3th in economic growth
12-Luxembourg: 4rd in freedom: 18th in economic growth
13-Denmark: 8th in freedom: 63th in economic growth
14-Spain: 31th in freedom: 56th in economic growth
15-South Korea: 53th in freedom: 12th in economic growth
16-Equatorial Guinea: 132th in freedom: 1st in economic growth
17-Sudan: No data :5th in economic growth
18-India:122th in freedom: 17th in growth
19-Maldives: No data: 6th in growth
20-Guyana: 7th in growth: 94th in economic freedom
21-Burma: 8th in growth: 150th in economic freedom
By Gothmog
#26397
-Looked at Maddison again. By 1913, Ireland had a per capita GDP near 50% of that of England and 4 times that of India and other colonial countries (whose income essetially stagnated from 1913 to 1950, proving the devastating effects of colonialist rule, while Ireland improved)
By Freedom
#26470
Some articles...no time for my own research...man i hate school




Ending Mass Poverty
by Ian Vásquez


Economic growth is the "only path to end mass poverty," says economist Ian Vásquez, who argues that redistribution or traditional poverty reduction programs have done little to relieve poverty. Vásquez writes that the higher the degree of economic freedom -- which consists of personal choice, protection of private property, and freedom of exchange -- the greater the reduction in poverty. Extending the system of property rights protection to include the property of poor people would be one of the most important poverty reduction strategies a nation could take, he says.
The historical record is clear: the single, most effective way to reduce world poverty is economic growth. Western countries began discovering this around 1820 when they broke with the historical norm of low growth and initiated an era of dramatic advances in material well-being. Living standards tripled in Europe and quadrupled in the United States in that century, improving at an even faster pace in the next 100 years. Economic growth thus eliminated mass poverty in what is today considered the developed world. Taking the long view, growth has also reduced poverty in other parts of the world: in 1820, about 75 percent of humanity lived on less than a dollar per day; today about 20 percent live under that amount.
Even a short-term view confirms that the recent acceleration of growth in many developing countries has reduced poverty, measured the same way. In the past 10 years, the percentage of poor people in the developing world fell from 29 to 24 percent. Despite that progress, however, the number of poor people has remained stubbornly high at around 1,200 million. And geographically, reductions in poverty have been uneven.
This mixed performance has prompted many observers to ask what factors other than growth reduce poverty and if growth is enough to accomplish that goal. Market reforms themselves have been questioned as a way of helping the poor. After all, many developing countries have liberalized their economies to varying degrees in the past decade.
But it would be a colossal mistake to lose focus on market-based growth and concentrate instead on redistribution or traditional poverty reduction programs that have done little by comparison to relieve poverty. Keeping the right focus is important for three reasons -- there is, in fact, a strong relationship between growth and poverty reduction, economic freedom causes growth, and most developing countries can still do much more in the way of policies and institutional reforms to help the poor.
The Importance of Growth
The pattern of poverty reduction we see around the world should not be surprising. It generally follows the relationship found by a recent World Bank study that looked at growth in 65 developing countries during the 1980s and 1990s. The share of people in poverty, defined as those living on less than a dollar per day, almost always declined in countries that experienced growth and increased in countries that experienced economic contractions. The faster the growth, the study found, the faster the poverty reduction, and vice versa. For example, an economic expansion in per capita income of 8.2 percent translated into a 6.1 reduction in the poverty rate. A contraction of 1.9 percent in output led to an increase of 1.5 percent in the poverty rate.
That relationship explains why some countries and regions have done better than others. "Between 1987 and 1998, there was only one region of the world that saw a dramatic fall in both the number of people and the proportion of the population living on less than a dollar a day. That region was East Asia," observes economist Martin Wolf. "But this was also the only region to see consistent and rapid growth in real incomes per head."
High growth allowed East Asia to reduce the share of its poor during this period from 26 to 15 percent and the number of poor from 417 million to 278 million people. With annual growth rates of nearly 9 percent since 1979, when it began introducing market reforms, China alone has pulled more than 100 million people out of poverty. The more modest but increasing growth rate in India during the past decade means that the outlook of the poor in the two countries that make up half of the developing world's population is noticeably improving.
Elsewhere the performance is less encouraging but follows the same pattern. Poverty rates rose in Eastern Europe and Central Asia, where economic activity declined sharply, and stayed the same in Latin America and sub-Saharan Africa, where growth was low or negligible.
Even within regions there are variations. Thus Mexico's per capita growth rates of 1.5 percent in the 1990s did not affect the share of people living in destitution, while Chile's 7 percent average growth rate from 1987 to 1998 reduced the poverty rate from 45 to 22 percent, according to the Institute for Liberty and Development based in Santiago.
Likewise, Vietnam stands out in Southeast Asia. With that country's per capita growth rates averaging about 6 percent in the 1990s, the World Bank reports that those living under the poverty line declined from 58 to 37 percent between 1993 and 1998. And Uganda's per capita growth of more than 4 percent in the 1990s reduced the share of people living below a minimum poverty line from 56 percent to 44 percent between 1992 and 1997. The Centre for the Study of African Economies at Oxford University concluded that "general growth accounts for most of the fall in poverty."
The dramatic impact of growth cannot be understated, even when differences in productivity rates are apparently small. To illustrate, Harvard economist Robert Barro notes that per capita income in the United States grew at an average 1.75 percent per year from 1870 to 1990, making Americans the richest people in the world. Had this country grown just one percentage point slower during that time period, U.S. per capita income levels would be about the same as Mexico's. Had the growth rate been just one percentage point higher, average U.S. income would be $60,841 -- three times the actual level.
The Importance of Economic Freedom
The West's escape from poverty did not occur by chance. Sustained growth over long periods of time took place in an environment that generally encouraged free enterprise and the protection of private property. Today, developing countries have an advantage. By adopting liberal economic policies, poor countries can achieve within one generation the kind of economic progress that it took rich countries 100 years to achieve. High growth is possible because poor countries will be catching up to rich countries, rather than forging a new path. Studies by both the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund confirm that countries such as China and others that have chosen to open their economies are indeed converging with the industrialized world.
The most comprehensive empirical study on the relationship between economic policies and prosperity is the Fraser Institute's "Economic Freedom of the World" annual report. It looks at more than 20 components of economic freedom, ranging from size of government to monetary and trade policy, in 123 countries over a 25-year period. The study finds a strong relationship between economic freedom and prosperity. Divided by quintiles, the freest economies have an average per capita income of $19,800 compared with $2,210 in the least free quintile. Freer economies also grow faster than less free economies. Per capita growth in the 1990s was 2.27 percent in the most free quintile, while it was -1.45 percent in the least free countries.
The Fraser study also found that economic freedom is strongly related to poverty reduction and other indicators of progress. The United Nations' Human Poverty Index is negatively correlated with the Fraser index of economic freedom. People living in the top 20 percent of countries in terms of economic freedom, moreover, tend to live about two decades longer than people in the bottom 20 percent. Lower infant mortality, higher literacy rates, lower corruption, and greater access to safe drinking water are also associated with increases in economic liberty. Indeed, the United Nations' Human Development Index, which measures various aspects of standards of living, correlates positively with greater economic freedom.
The implications for the poor are impressive. Economists Steve Hanke and Stephen Walters examined the leading empirical studies on the relationship between economic freedom and prosperity and concluded that a 10 percent increase in economic freedom tends to increase per capita gross national product by 7.4 to 13.6 percent. Since developing countries can still increase their levels of economic freedom substantially, and some have by 100 percent or more in the past two decades, the payoff of enhanced liberty can be seen not only in terms of growth but also in terms of a range of human development indicators. Hanke and Walters found, for example, that an increase in per capita income from $500 to $1,000 produces a rise in life expectancy of about 6 percent. Indeed, high growth creates the wealth that makes it possible for countries to invest in health, education, and other human needs that are an essential part of continued growth. Nor are those benefits shared unequally. The Fraser study found that there is no correlation between economic freedom and inequality, while a World Bank study has found that the incomes of the poorest 20 percent of the population rise proportionately with the average rise in income.
Toward More Effective Poverty Reduction
Although the collapse of central planning forced many countries to abandon inward-looking economic policies in the 1990s, most of the developing world is still far from adopting a coherent set of policies consistent with economic freedom. Russia may have dumped communism, but in terms of economic freedom the Fraser Institute ranks the country 117 out of 123 nations. Even countries such as Argentina and Mexico that have done much to liberalize their economies have clung to policy remnants of the past, with devastating consequences for the poor. Mexico's peso crisis of 1994-95, for example, resulted from monetary and fiscal policies during an election year that were thoroughly inconsistent with market economics.
Attention to market-oriented macroeconomic policies is well founded, particularly since they benefit the poor. That is especially so of two such policies -- reducing inflation and the level of spending -- which disproportionately favor the poor. Much less attention, however, has been paid to institutional reforms and the microeconomic environment. Three areas stand out: the rule of law, the level of bureaucratic regulation, and the private property rights of the poor.
A legal system capable of enforcing contracts and protecting persons and their property rights in an evenhanded manner is central to both economic freedom and progress. Indeed, the sustainability of a market economy -- and of market reforms themselves -- rests largely on the application of the rule of law. Yet the rule of law is conspicuously missing in much of the developing world. The 2001 "Economic Freedom of the World" report, which includes a more comprehensive index of economic freedom for 58 countries, takes this measure into account. It finds that Latin American countries rank especially low in this area. Also at the bottom of the list are transition countries such as Russia and Ukraine. Were reliable data available for African countries, they would no doubt receive low ratings as well.
The absence of the rule of law is especially unfortunate for the poor, not only because they have fewer private resources to protect their rights, but also because the rule of law in itself is related to economic growth. Robert Barro created an index that measured the rule of law on a scale of 0 to 6 and found that a country's growth rate increases by half a percentage point with each increment in his index. Because the rule of law provides essential protections for the poor, sustains a market exchange system, and promotes growth, it may well be the most important ingredient of economic prosperity.
Another much neglected area in need of reform is regulation. Here again the Fraser Institute's comprehensive index found that the freedom to operate a business and compete in the market is circumscribed in much of the developing world. The same countries that ranked low in the rule of law area ranked low in this area. To have an idea of the bureaucratic burden with which people in the developing world must contend, consider the cases of Canada, Bolivia, and Hungary. According to a study by the National Bureau of Economic Research, it takes two days, two bureaucratic procedures, and $280 to open a business in Canada. By contrast, an entrepreneur in Bolivia must pay $2,696 in fees, wait 82 business days, and go through 20 procedures to do the same. In Hungary the same operation takes 53 business days, 10 procedures, and $3,647. Such costly barriers favor big firms at the expense of small enterprises, where most jobs are created, and push a large proportion of the developing world's population into the informal economy.
The informal economy in the developing world is large due to another major factor. The private property rights of the poor are not legally recognized. Peruvian economist Hernando de Soto has documented how poor people around the world have no security in their assets because they lack legal title to their property. In rural Peru, for example, 70 percent of poor people's property is not recognized by the state. The lack of such legal protection severely limits the wealth-creating potential that the poor would otherwise have were they allowed to participate within the legal framework of the market. Without secure private property rights, the poor cannot use collateral to get a loan, cannot take out insurance, and find it difficult to plan in the long term.
Ending what amounts to legal discrimination would permit poor people to benefit fully from the market system and allow the poor to use their considerable assets to create wealth. Indeed, as de Soto has shown, the poor are already asset rich. According to him, the assets of the poor are worth 40 times the value of all foreign aid since 1945. The wealth of Haiti's poor, for example, is more than 150 times greater than all foreign investment in that country since its independence in 1804. In the limited places that poor people's property has been registered, the results have been impressive. Where registration was done in Peru, new businesses were created, production increased, asset values rose 200 percent, and credit became available.
Extending the system of property rights protection to include the property of poor people is the most important social reform that developing countries can undertake. It is a reform that has been almost completely ignored around the world, yet it would directly affect the poor and produce dramatic results for literally thousands of millions of people.
Keeping the Right Focus
Countries have ended mass poverty only by following policies that encourage economic growth. But that growth must be self-sustaining to translate into enduring increases in wealth. Policies of forced industrialization or state-led development may produce high growth for a time, but history has shown that such episodes are followed by economic contraction. Economic freedom, by contrast, shows a strong relationship with prosperity and growth over time. Fortunately, many developing countries are following that path, producing high and rapid growth and showing that it is good for the poor. Their experience may create a demonstration effect for the majority of nations that are in many ways still economically unfree.
All developing nations can do more to increase growth. Establishing the rule of law, reducing barriers that hamper entrepreneurship and competition, and recognizing the property rights of the poor are three reforms that go beyond the liberalization measures that many countries have already introduced. Those reforms not only contribute to economic growth; they increase the effectiveness of growth in reducing poverty. Policy-makers in rich and poor countries alike should not lose focus on the promise of growth. It remains the only path to end mass poverty.

The Blessings and Challenges of Globalization.
by Daniel T. Griswold

The evidence of globalization can be seen everywhere: in the home, in the workplace, in the discount stores, in the newspapers and business journals, in the flow of monthly government statistics, and in academic literature. The backlash was on display in Seattle in November 1999, when thousands of protesters took to the streets to demonstrate against the ministerial meeting of the World Trade Organization (WTO).

A short definition of globalization is "the growing liberalization of international trade and investment, and the resulting increase in the integration of national economies." Economist David Henderson of the Melbourne Business School expands the definition into five related but distinct parts:

* the increasing tendency for firms to think, plan, operate, and invest for the future with reference to markets and opportunities across the world as a whole;

* the growing ease and cheapness of international communications, with the Internet the leading aspect;

* the trend toward closer international economic integration, resulting in the diminished importance of political boundaries. This trend is fueled partly by the first two trends, but even more powerfully by official policies aimed at trade and investment liberalization;

* the apparently growing significance of issues and problems extending beyond national boundaries and the resulting impetus to deal with them through some form of internationally concerted action; and

* the tendency toward uniformity (or "harmonization"), by which norms, standards, rules, and practices are defined and enforced with respect to regions, or the world as a whole, rather than within the bounds of nation-states.1

Globalization can be seen most clearly in the quickening pace and scope of international commerce. Global exports as a share of global domestic product have increased from 14 percent in 1970 to 24 percent today,2 and the growth of trade has consistently outpaced growth in global output. In the United States, the ratio of two-way trade and investment income flows as a share of GDP has roughly tripled since the 1960s. Annual global flows of foreign direct investment surged to a record $ 400 billion in 1997, with 37 percent directed to less developed countries (LDCs), up from 7 percent in 1990.3 In the 1970s, daily foreign exchange transactions averaged $ 10 billion to $ 20 billion; today, the average daily activity has reached more than $ 1.5 trillion.4

The expansion of international trade and foreign investment has not been the result of some grand design imposed on the global economy. It has been an ad hoc, decentralized, bottom-up process resulting from two developments of the 1980s: the collapse of global communism and the demise of the Third World's romance with import substitution. The fall of the Berlin Wall and the final disintegration of the Soviet empire two years later released 400 million people from the grip of centrally commanded and essentially closed economic systems. Meanwhile, the debt crisis of 1982 and the resulting "Lost Decade" of the 1980s imposed a painful hangover on many Third World nations that had tried and failed to reach prosperity by shunning foreign capital and by protecting and subsidizing domestic "infant" industries. Beginning with Chile in the mid-1970s and China later that decade, LDCs from Mexico and Argentina to India more recently have been opening their markets and welcoming foreign investment. The globalization of the last decade has not been the result of a blind faith in markets imposed from above but of the utter exhaustion of any alternative vision.

In contrast to those failed policies, certain countries have managed to dramatically improve their living standards by deregulating their domestic economies and opening up to global markets. The Four Tigers of East Asia--Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, and South Korea--are the most prominent examples. From typical Third World poverty in the 1950s, each has achieved a standard of living today equivalent to that of industrialized nations, with per-capita incomes in Hong Kong and Singapore rivaling those of the wealthiest Western nations.

The relative success of openness as a policy, compared with protectionism, has spurred a global movement toward unilateral trade liberalization. Since the mid-1980s, sixty LDCs have unilaterally lowered their barriers to trade. LDCs have flocked to join the WTO. Today more than three-quarters of its members are LDCs, with another twenty waiting in line to join.5 The move to trade liberalization has been accompanied by investment liberalization, with more than 90 percent of national policy changes in the last decade being in the direction of more openness toward foreign investment.6

THE BLESSINGS OF GLOBALIZATION

Beyond all the impressive numbers about the extent of globalization, what kind of impact is it having on national economies? There are at least three fundamental blessings of globalization on nations that embrace it: faster economic growth, reductions in poverty, and more fertile soil for democracy.

The greatest beneficiaries of globalization are the long-suffering consumers in those nations that had been "protected" from global competition. Globalization expands the range of choice, improves product quality, and exerts downward pressure on prices. It delivers an immediate gain to workers by raising the real value of their wages. It transfers wealth from formerly protected producers to newly liberated consumers, with the gains to consumers exceeding the loss to producers because the deadweight losses to the economy are recaptured through efficiency gains.

Under autarky, consumers are often cursed with poor service and overpriced and low-quality goods because there is no real competition to spur domestic producers to meet the demands of their consumers. This explains the poor quality of cars sold by protected domestic producers in such places as India, where the standard Ambassador car is based on the Morris Oxford, a make of car that went out of style in Britain four decades ago.

LDCs have the most to gain from engaging in the global economy. First, they gain access to much larger markets, both for imports and exports. On the import side, consumers gain access to a dramatically larger range of goods and services, raising their real standard of living. Domestic producers gain access to a wider range and better quality of intermediate inputs at lower prices. On the export side, domestic industries can enjoy a quantum leap in economies of scale by serving global markets rather than only a confined and underdeveloped domestic market.

Second, LDCs that open themselves up to international trade and investment gain access to a much higher level of technology. This confers on LDCs a "latecomer's advantage": rather than bearing the cost of expensive, up-front research and development, poor countries can import the technology off the shelf. They can incorporate new technology by importing capital equipment that embodies the latest advances and computers with the latest software. Subsidiaries of multinational companies also bring with them new production techniques and employee training that bolster the host nation's stock of human capital.

Third, engagement in the global economy provides capital to fuel future growth. Most LDCs are people-rich and capital-poor. In a few countries in Asia, the level of domestic savings has been high enough to finance domestic investment, but typically the domestic pool of savings in an LDC is inadequate. Global capital markets can fill the gap, allowing poor nations to accelerate their pace of growth. In 1998, $ 166 billion in foreign direct investment flowed from the advanced economies to the less developed. A poor country that closes its door or fails to maintain sound domestic policies will forfeit the immense benefits this capital can bring.

Fourth, openness to the global economy can provide the infrastructure a developing economy needs for growth. Foreign capital can finance more traditional types of infrastructure, such as port facilities, power generation, and an internal transportation network, just as British capital helped to finance America's network of canals and railroads in the nineteenth century. But just as importantly, multinational companies can provide an infrastructure of what could be called "enabling services," such as telecommunications, insurance, accounting, and banking. As China and India have realized, a protected and inefficient service sector weighs down an entire economy, retarding the development of manufacturing and other industries. LDCs need to shed the mistaken idea that opening their economies up to international service competition is a "concession" to be made to gain access to farm and manufacturing markets in the advanced economies. In reality, liberalizing their service sectors by opening them to foreign competition is a favor LDCs can do for themselves.

Fifth, engagement in the global economy encourages governments to follow more sensible economic policies. Sovereign nations remain free to follow whatever economic policies their governments choose, but globalization has raised the cost that must be paid for bad policies. With capital more mobile than ever, countries that insist on following antimarket policies will find themselves being dealt out of the global competition for investment. As a consequence, nations have a greater incentive to choose policies that encourage foreign investment and domestic, market-led growth. New York Times columnist Thomas Freidman, in The Lexus and the Olive, his 1999 book on globalization, describes these progrowth policies as "the Golden Straitjacket." The increasingly manifest rewards of engagement encourage nations to unilaterally restrict the scope of government action. As Friedman explains:

To fit into the Golden Straitjacket a country must either adopt, or be seen as moving toward, the following golden rules: making the private sector the primary engine of its economic growth, maintaining a low rate of inflation and price stability, shrinking the size of its state bureaucracy, maintaining as close to a balanced budget as possible, if not a surplus; eliminating and lowering tariffs on imported goods, removing restrictions on foreign investment, getting rid of quotas and domestic monopolies, increasing exports, privatizing state-owned industries and utilities, deregulating capital markets, making its currency convertible, opening its industries, stock, and bond markets to direct foreign ownership and investment, deregulating its economy to promote as much domestic competition as possible, eliminating government corruption, subsidies and kickbacks as much as possible, opening its banking and telecommunications systems to private ownership and competition, and allowing its citizens to choose from an array of competing pension options and foreign-run pension and mutual funds.7
While globalization may confront government officials with more difficult choices, the result for their citizens is greater individual freedom. In this sense, globalization acts as a check on governmental power, making it more difficult for governments to abuse the freedom and property of their citizens.

Any casual survey of the world today will confirm that nations relatively open to trade tend to be more prosperous than nations that are relatively closed. The wealthiest nations and regions of the world- -western Europe, the United States, Canada, Japan, Hong Kong, Taiwan, South Korea, Singapore--are all trade-orientated. Their producers, with a few notable exceptions, must compete against other multinational producers in the global marketplace. In contrast, the poorest regions of the world--the Indian subcontinent and sub-Saharan Africa--remain (despite recent, halting reforms) the least friendly to foreign trade. And those countries that have moved decisively toward openness--Chile, China, and Poland, among others--have reaped real (and, in the case of China, spectacular) gains in living standards.

Systematic studies confirm a strong link between openness and economic growth.8 A study of 117 countries by Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner found that open economies grew much faster than closed economies. Specifically, the authors found that the developing countries that maintained open economies throughout the 1970s and '80s grew at an average annual rate of 4.5 percent, compared with an average growth rate of 0.7 percent for closed economies. As a result, the open developing economies tended to converge toward the slower-growing rich economies, while relatively closed economies did not converge.9

A more recent study, by Jeffrey Frankel and David Romer, produced similar results. The authors found that trade exerts "a qualitatively large and robust E positive effect on income." In their study of 150 countries, they concluded that increasing the ratio of trade to gross domestic product by 1 percentage point raises income per person by between 0.5 and 2 percent.10 The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) concluded that nations relatively open to trade grew on average twice as fast as those relatively closed to trade.11

HOPE FOR THE WORLD'S POOREST

Globalization offers hope to the world's poorest. Just as more open trade tends to promote economic growth, growth in turn leads to poverty reduction. A World Bank study found that periods of sustained economic growth are almost always accompanied by reductions in poverty. Specifically, the study found that poverty fell in 77 of the 88 decade- long periods of growth covered by the survey.12

The greatest reductions in poverty in the last twenty years have occurred in nations that have moved decisively toward openness and domestic liberalization. The most spectacular gains have been realized in East Asia. Between 1993 and '96, the number of people living in absolute poverty--what the World Bank defines as less than $ 1 per day-- declined in the region from 432 million to 267 million. In China alone, the number of poor people so defined fell by 150 million between 1990 and '97.13 The 1997--98 financial crisis that began in East Asia brought a temporary halt to this progress, but poverty rates in the hardest-hit countries--Korea, Thailand, and Indonesia--have begun to decline back toward their precrisis levels. Globally, the number of people living in absolute poverty has declined in the 1990s to an estimated 1.2 billion in 1998.14

Globalization facilitates the spread of modern medicine, which has helped to extend life expectancy and reduce infant mortality in rich and poor countries alike. On average, life expectancy in developing countries rose from 55 years in 1970 to 65 years in 1997. This good news is tempered by the fact that life expectancy has actually fallen in thirty-three LDCs since 1990, in large part because of AIDS epidemics, and remains far behind the OECD average of 78 years. Infant mortality rates in Asia and sub-Saharan Africa have fallen by about 10 percent since 1990.15

Opponents of globalization try to blame poverty in the world on the spread of trade and investment liberalization. But those regions where poverty and inequality have been the most visible and intransigent for decades--Latin America, sub-Saharan Africa, and the Indian subcontinent--for most of that time self-consciously followed policies of economic centralization and isolation.

FERTILE SOIL FOR POLITICAL FREEDOM

By raising the general standard of living, free trade helps people achieve higher levels of education and to gain access to alternative sources of information. It helps to create a larger and more independently minded middle class that can form the backbone of more representative forms of government. The wealth created from expanded trade can help to nurture and sustain civil institutions that can offer ideas and influence outside government. Engagement in the global economy exposes citizens to new ideas and new social and business arrangements. In his book Business as a Calling, Michael Novak explains the linkage with what he calls "the wedge theory":

Capitalist practices, runs the theory, bring contact with the ideas and practices of the free societies, generate the economic growth that gives political confidence to a rising middle class, and raise up successful business leaders who come to represent a political alternative to military or party leaders. In short, capitalist firms wedge a democratic camel's nose under the authoritarian tent.16

The wedge theory seems to be working in practice: As a general rule, the citizens of nations that are more open economically tend to enjoy other liberties as well. The relationship can be confirmed by comparing cross-country data measuring economic openness and political/civil liberties. For the political and civil data, I have used recent ratings from Freedom House, which classifies the nations of the world as free, partly free, or not free.17 Then I compared the Freedom House scores with international economic freedom as measured in the study Economic Freedom of the World: 1998/1999 Interim Report, written by James Gwartney and Robert Lawson. The authors rated nations according to their level of taxation on trade, the size of the trade sector, exchange rate controls, and restraints on capital mobility, with a rating of 10 representing maximum openness.18

Comparing these two sets of data confirms that nations that respect human rights tend to be relatively open to commerce with the rest of the world. Nations that are classified by Freedom House as being free scored an average of 7.9 on the scale of economic openness. Those that are partly free scored a less open 6.7, and those that are not free scored the lowest, 5.4 (see fig. 1). If we start at the other axis we find that, of those countries in the top third of the Gwartney-Lawson scale of economic openness, 84 percent earned a political/civil ranking of "free." Of those in the middle third according to economic openness, 57 percent were free, but in the bottom third, only 22 percent were free. In other words, citizens who enjoy the freedom to engage in international commerce are about four times more likely to be free from political and civil oppression than those who do not enjoy such freedom.

Globalization and the growth it spurs have contributed to expanded political and civil freedom in a number of countries. Taiwan and South Korea were essentially dictatorships two decades ago, but they are now governed by elected legislatures and presidents. Political debate in those countries is robust, and civil liberties are more secure than ever. A share of the credit for political reform must be given to economic liberalization and the educated middle class it helped to create and nurture. In Latin America, the movement toward economic liberalization has been intertwined with a flowering of representative government. Chile, a leader in economic reform, now enjoys one of the region's most stable democracies. A decade of dramatic economic reform in Mexico has helped lay the foundation for a more open political system, including Mexico's first competitive presidential primary within the Institutional Revolutionary Party.

Skeptics of the link between economic and political reform routinely point to India and Singapore to refute the thesis. These countries are clearly outliers in the scatterplot: Singapore is one of the world's most open economies but its government remains authoritarian, while India remains relatively closed economically yet is ruled by democracy. Exceptions, however, do not negate a clear trend. And even these two notable exceptions seem to be migrating toward the trend line, with India opening up to trade and foreign investment since its balance of payments crisis in 1991, and the Singapore government gradually loosening its controls on civil society.

THE CHALLENGES OF GLOBALIZATION

The advance of globalization has not been a smooth or a pain-free process. The changes it has caused, or is perceived to have caused, have spurred a political backlash--dramatically evident in the street protests that plagued the WTO ministerial in Seattle. Two of the most common complaints against globalization are that it has undermined labor and environmental standards, and that it has exacerbated the gap between rich and poor, both among and within countries.

Critics of globalization warn of a destructive "race to the bottom," as advanced nations are forced to weaken labor and environmental standards to compete with less-regulated producers in developing nations. This theory rests on the assumption that lower standards give LDCs a significant advantage in attracting global capital and gaining export markets at the expense of more developed countries. The OECD has found that, in practice, a lack of core labor standards plays no significant role in attracting foreign investment or in enhancing export performance. The OECD did find strong evidence "that there is a positive association over time between sustained trade reforms and improvements in core standards."19

In other words, trade liberalization encourages higher standards, not lower standards. If anything, the real race may be toward the top. For reasons of internal efficiency as well as public perceptions, multinational companies tend to impose higher standards on their overseas production plants than those prevailing in local markets, thus raising average standards in the host country. Free trade and domestic liberalization--and the faster growth they create--are the best ways to encourage higher standards. As per capita incomes rise in less developed countries, so does the domestic political demand for higher standards, and the ability of the productive sector to pay for them. Punishing LDCs with trade sanctions would only cripple their long-term ability to raise domestic labor and environmental standards.

Some environmental activists complain that the global trading system, as embodied in the WTO, favors free trade at the expense of environmental protection. But WTO rules place no restraints on the ability of a member government to impose any environmental regulations determined to be necessary to protect its own environment from domestically produced or imported products. Article XX of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994, the basic charter of the WTO, plainly states that members may impose trade restrictions "necessary to protect human, animal, or plant health." The Sanitary and Phytosanitary Agreement of the Uruguay Round does require that such restrictions be based on sound scientific evidence--a commonsense requirement necessary to discourage the use of health and safety issues as a cover for protectionism.

If WTO members are found to be in violation of their commitments, they remain free as sovereign nations to simply ignore any adverse WTO rulings against domestic regulations that impact trade. A prominent example is the European Union's ban on the sale of beef from cattle treated with growth hormones. The EU has repeatedly lost in the WTO, but it has no plans to lift its ban, even though it has produced no scientifically sound evidence that the banned beef poses any hazard to public health. The United States retaliated against the EU in May 1999 by imposing sanctions on $ 117 million worth of imports from Europe, but retaliation as a weapon of trade disputes existed long before the WTO.

Antitrade environmental activists complain that several decisions by the WTO have undercut U.S. environmental regulations. In the so-called Shrimp-Turtle case, the WTO ruled against a U.S. ban on shrimp from countries the United States judged were not adequately protecting sea turtles from being caught and killed in shrimp nets. In an earlier, similar case, the WTO had ruled against a U.S. ban on tuna from Mexico that the United States claims was caught through a process that endangers dolphins. Environmental critics of the WTO point to these two cases as proof of their claim.

In both these cases, however, the United States remains free to simply ignore the WTO ruling and continue enforcing the law as is. The affected nations could in theory retaliate with trade restrictions of their own if the United States refuses to comply, but that option would always exist even if the WTO did not. And in the case of the Shrimp- Turtle decision, it was not the law itself that ran afoul of WTO rules but the discriminatory way the United States went about implementing it, for example giving Latin American suppliers more time than Asian suppliers to comply with the law.

Expanding trade is not merely compatible with high standards of environmental quality but can lead directly to their improvement. As a country sees its standard of living rise through economic liberalization and trade expansion, its industry can more readily afford to control emissions and its citizens have more to spend on the "luxury good" of improved environmental quality, above what they need for subsistence. And as economic growth creates a growing, better- educated middle class, the political demand for pollution abatement rises. Today the most restrictive environmental laws are maintained in developed countries that are relatively open to trade.

This helps explain the so-called Environmental Kuznets Curve, where environmental quality in a developing nation initially deteriorates as the economy begins to industrialize but then improves after its citizens reach a certain standard of living. Research by Alan Krueger and Gene Grossman indicates that the turning point occurs at about $ 5,000 per capita: "We find no evidence that environmental quality deteriorates steadily with economic growth. Rather, for most indicators, economic growth brings an initial phase of deterioration followed by a subsequent phase of improvement." By $ 8,000 per-capita income, the authors found, almost all the pollutant categories had begun to improve.20

The United States itself is a classic example of the benign effect of trade and growth on the environment. It has simultaneously one of the most open economies and one of the cleanest environments in the world. In the past decade, the United States has continued to open its economy further, signing the North American Free Trade Agreement and shepherding the creation of the World Trade Organization. Meanwhile, two-way trade and foreign investment continue to climb as a percentage of GDP. This liberalization of international trade and investment has been accompanied by ever-rising environmental standards. According to the President's Council on Environmental Quality, mean ambient concentrations of both sulfur dioxide and carbon monoxide in the atmosphere of the United States have dropped by nearly 40 percent since 1988. During that same period, the annual number of "bad air days" in major U.S. cities has dropped by two-thirds. The direct discharge of toxic water pollutants is down dramatically as well. Since the early 1970s, during a time of growing globalization of the U.S. economy, real spending by government and business on the environment and natural resource protection has doubled.21

Despite the rhetoric heard on the streets in Seattle, expanding global trade has not spurred a race to the bottom on environmental regulation or quality. In fact, the evidence points in the opposite direction.

THE GAP BETWEEN RICH AND POOR

Another challenge of globalization is the perception that economic liberalization has exacerbated the gap between rich and poor countries, and between the rich and poor within countries that have liberalized. The perception that the gap has been growing, both among and within nations, is broadly true. The connection with globalization is much less clear.

While some previously poor countries have managed to close the gap with the more advanced economies, a disturbingly large number of countries have fallen further behind. According to the World Bank, the ratio of income per capita in the richest countries compared with that in the poorest rose from 11 in 1870 to 38 in 1960 to 52 in 1985.22 Concern about the "marginalization" of poor countries in the global economic system has rightly focused on sub-Saharan Africa. Since 1976, the region's share in world trade has fallen from 3 percent to slightly more than 1 percent in the 1990s.23 While the flow of foreign direct investment to LDCs has risen dramatically in the 1990s, sub-Saharan Africa has been almost entirely overlooked. But the phenomenon of marginalization has not been a random event.

Poor nations that have fallen further behind the rich nations are almost uniformly those that have clung to state-directed and inward- oriented economic policies. Sub-Saharan Africa has lagged behind the rest of the world in economic growth in significant part because its markets remain among the most closed in the world. Its governments have neglected domestic infrastructure such as roads and have distorted their domestic economies with subsidies, high taxes, and regulations. Granted, many African nations must also bear the burden of civil and tribal strife, poor soil, and inaccessible geography. But domestic economic policy must be considered a key variable in explaining the region's failure to develop. Those African nations that have implemented more open, stable, and market-friendly policies in the last decade--such as Uganda, Botswana, and Mauritius--have achieved growth rates exceeding those of the advanced nations.

The most obvious variable that separates countries that are closing the gap from those falling further behind is their own domestic policy choices. Simply put, nations that adopt the "Golden Straitjacket" begin to catch up with the advanced economies, while those that reject it become increasingly marginalized. In their Economic Freedom of the World: 1997 Annual Report, Gwartney and Lawson found strong empirical evidence linking growth rates to economic freedom. The authors measured seventeen categories of economic policy for each of 115 countries-- covering monetary policy, property rights, government spending and regulation, and restraints on foreign trade. They found a strong correlation between economic freedom and both economic growth and per- capita GDP. The authors found that each quintile of greater economic freedom corresponded with faster growth and higher per-capita GDP. Nations in the top quintile in 1995 grew almost three times faster (2.9 percent annually) on average than those in the middle quintile (1.1 percent). Those in the bottom quintile saw their economies shrink an average of 1.9 percent.24

There is nothing inherent in the process of globalization that would cause the gulf between rich and poor nations to expand. In fact, the access to capital, new technology, and larger markets that comes with global integration should be expected to accelerate the convergence of less developed regions of the world and to make global trade and wealth less concentrated across countries. This dynamic has been at work inside the United States, which has itself been a continent-sized free- trade area for more than two centuries. At the turn of the last century, in 1900, per-capita income varied widely across the four major regions of the United States. While incomes in the Midwest were close to the national average, at 103 percent, incomes in the Northeast were 139 percent above the national average and those in the West were 153 percent above. In contrast, income levels in the South were only 54 percent of the national average. One century later--thanks in large measure to the free flow of goods, capital, and people within U.S. borders--regional disparities have shrunk dramatically. Today, income levels in the Northeast are only 117 percent above the national average, incomes in the Midwest and West are within 2 percentage points of the national average, and incomes in the South as a share of the national average have risen to 90 percent.25

Evidence of a similar trend exists among countries that have chosen to join the global economy. A 1998 study sponsored by the WTO found that global trade and investment flows have actually become less concentrated in the last two decades when adjusted for the growth in world trade. Moreover, the authors found that the concentration of trade and financial flows has fallen among countries that have more rapidly liberalized, whereas it has increased among those that have integrated more slowly. "We argue this shows that marginalization of individual countries from world markets can be mostly explained by inward-looking domestic policies," they concluded, "and therefore that marginalization is not inherent to the globalization process."26

Of course, the advanced economies have not always been helpful. Despite progress in the post-war era, advanced-economy trade barriers remain stubbornly high against clothing, textiles, and agricultural goods, the very products in which LDCs have a natural comparative advantage. A recent study by Thomas Hertel of Purdue University and Will Martin of the World Bank found that the average tariff that rich countries impose on manufacturing goods from poor countries is four times higher than the average tariff rich countries impose on each other's goods.27 One of the many disappointments left in the wake of the failed WTO talks in Seattle has been the indefinite postponement of negotiations to lower barriers to poor-country exports. It would be wrong, however, to blame advanced-country trade barriers for the lack of economic progress in so many LDCs. After all, the Four Tigers of East Asia managed to hop on the income-convergence conveyor belt in the face of advanced-country trade barriers that were even higher than they are today.

For poorer nations, the global economy has become like one of those giant conveyor belts that speed passengers through airport terminals. Globalization can accelerate a country's development, but only if its policymakers allow its citizens to hop onboard by opening the economy to international trade and investment. This conveyor belt of growth provides new technology, investment capital, domestic competition, expanding export markets, and powerful incentives for further domestic policy reform. The result is faster growth and dramatic improvements in living standards within a generation or two--as we have seen most strikingly in the Far East. The fact that some nations insist on walking their own, uphill, isolated, and often dead-end path is not the fault of globalization but of their own policymakers.

The story of income inequality within nations is more complicated. The trend within the United States and other developed nations has been toward a wider earnings gap between the lowest- and the highest-paid workers. The gap has been driven primarily by a difference in worker skills rather than by international trade. An information-based economy will naturally produce jobs that require more specialized and technical skills than a less developed economy, which is more weighted toward agriculture and industry. As a result, in the United States in the last twenty-five years, the gap in income has been increasing between workers with college degrees and those with only high school diplomas.

International trade has probably contributed something to this trend in the United States, because trade should in theory accelerate the transition toward industries that rely more intensively on high-skilled labor. But the primary engine of change in the U.S. economy during that time has been technological innovation.

The relatively larger importance of technological change compared with trade can be seen in recent trends of job displacement. U.S. Labor Department surveys show that three-quarters of Americans displaced from their jobs in 1995--97 were working in sectors of the economy that are relatively insulated from trade.28 Even in the more trade-intensive manufacturing sector, technological change rivals trade as the principal engine of labor-market change. International trade is often blamed for job displacement in manufacturing when in fact the cause is rising productivity. This explains why the number of workers employed in manufacturing in the United States has remained stable in the 1990s at slightly more than eighteen million, at a time when manufacturing output has been rising an average of 3.8 percent a year in the decade (and 5.5 percent a year since 1994).

As with employment, technology is also the chief explanatory variable of changes in income inequality. William Cline, in a study on the impact of trade on wages, concluded that international trade and immigration "are unlikely to have been the dominant forces in rising wage inequality."29 After surveying the literature and employing his own Trade and Income Distribution Equilibrium model, Cline concludes that skills-based technological change is by far the largest identifiable contributor to the growth in income inequality. International trade and immigration together "contribute only about one-tenth of the gross (total) unequalizing forces at work over this period."30

If curbing inequality is the aim, trade policy is a poorly suited instrument for achieving it. The right response to this growing demand for higher skills is not to stifle change through trade barriers but to raise the general skill level of the workforce. Instead of a futile effort to "save" the jobs of yesterday, the focus should be on preparing workers to meet the rising demands of the labor market for specialized skills.

EXPANDING ECONOMIC LIBERTY

Globalization is really just shorthand for expanding economic liberty across international borders. The debate it has spawned is the repackaging, on a global scale, of the long-running argument over whether the way to prosperity is through free markets or centralized government planning, or some "third way" between the two. If you believe free markets unleash forces that are destructive to human happiness and must be controlled by active government intervention, you will tend to see globalization as a threat. If you believe that free markets, operating within a rule of law, are essentially self- regulating and lead, in the words of Adam Smith, "as if by an invisible hand" to a greater general prosperity, then you will tend to see globalization as a blessing.

The argument that globalization is much more the latter than the former is supported not only by economic theory but by decades of hard-earned experience. A growing majority of nations have made their peace with globalization based not on whim or blind ideology but on the manifest failure of any alternative. They have come to realize that the spread of free markets and the institutions that support them offer the best hope that the fruits of prosperity can be shared by a wider circle of mankind.
Daniel T. Griswold is associate director of the Center for Trade Policy Studies at the Cato Institute

This article originally appeared in The World and I.


Notes
1.David Henderson, "The Changing International Economic Order: Rival Visions for the Coming Millennium," Melbourne Business School, 9 Sept. 1999.

2.Figures quoted by Alan Greenspan, chairman, Federal Reserve Board of Governors, "Technology and Trade," Speech before the Dallas Ambassadors forum, 16 Apr. 1999, http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs ... 990416.htm

3.United Nations, World Investment Report: 1998 (hereafter WIR:1998), 9.

4.United Nations, Human Development Report: 1999, 25.

5.Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Policy Coherence Matters, (Paris: OECD, 1999), 45.

6.United Nations, WIR:1998, 57.

7.Thomas Friedman, The Lexus and the Olive Tree (New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 1999), 86--87.

8.One problem with these cross-country studies of growth and trade is that trade liberalization is seldom an isolated event. LDCs liberalize in the context of broader economic reforms, which often include selling state-owned industries; reducing government taxation, spending, and borrowing; and deregulating domestic prices and production. This poses the challenge of determining the source of faster growth. Another methodological challenge is in measuring openness. There is no standard statistical measure of a nation's openness. What is clear is a general correlation between openness, under various definitions, and economic performance.

9.Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner, "Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1 (1995).

10.Jeffrey Frankel and David Romer, "Does Trade Cause Growth?" American Economic Review, June 1999, 379--99.

11.Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Open Markets Matter: The Benefits of Trade and Investment Liberalization, 1998, 10.

12.K. Deininger and L. Squire, "A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality," World Bank Economic Review 10:3, 565--91.

13.World Bank, Social Indicators, www.worldbank.org/poverty/data/trends/. Hereafter referred to as Social Indicators.

14.Social Indicators.

15.Social Indicators.

16.Michael Novak, Business as a Calling (New York: Free Press, 1996), 161.

17.Freedom House, Freedom in the World 1998--99, www.freedomhouse.org/survey99/tables/indeptab.html

18.James Gwartney and Robert Lawson, Economic Freedom of the World: 1998/1999 Interim Report (Vancouver, B.C.: Fraser Institute, 1998), 76--78.

19.OECD, Trade, Employment and Labor Standards: A Study of Core Workers' Rights and International Trade (Paris: OECD, 1996), 12--13.

20.Gene Grossman and Alan Krueger, "Economic Growth and the Environment," National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. W4634, Feb. 1994.

21.Council on Environmental Quality, Environmental Quality: 1997 Report (Washington), 86--89.

22.Social Indicators.

23.OECD, Policy, 60.

24.James Gwartney, Robert Lawson, and Walter Block, Economic Freedom of the World: 1975--95 (Vancouver, B.C.: Fraser Institute, 1996), xxii.

25.Joint Economic Committee of Congress, "The U.S. Economy at the Beginning and End of the Twentieth Century," Dec. 1999, 8.

26.Patrick Low, Marcelo Olarreaga, and Javier Suarez, "Does Globalization Cause a Higher Concentration of International Trade and Investment Flows?" World Trade Organization, Staff Working Paper ERAD-- 98--08, Aug. 1988, 22.

27."White Man's Shame," Economist, 25 Sept. 1999, 89.

28.Daniel Griswold, "Trade, Jobs, and Manufacturing: Why (Almost All) U.S. Workers Should Welcome Imports," Cato Trade Briefing Paper No. 6, 30 Sept. 1999, 11.

29.William Cline, "Trade and Income Distribution: The Debate and New Evidence," Institution for International Economics (Washington), International Economic Policy Brief No. 99--7, 3.

30.Cline, "Trade," 5.
By Gothmog
#26865
reduction strategies a nation could take, he says.
The historical record is clear: the single, most effective way to reduce world poverty is economic growth. Western countries began discovering this around 1820 when they broke with the historical norm of low growth and initiated an era of dramatic advances in material well-being.


-This is not some miracle of "freedom", but largely the result of massive scale of exploitation of Asian powers (mainly China and India, which were the largest economies in the world by then, and whose economy declined steadily in the 130 subsequent years until the communist revolution in China and the independence of India). This dramatic acceleration of growth was coincident with the Opium war and British colonialism in India. That´s a story the capitalists chhose to forget....

Living standards tripled in Europe and quadrupled in the United States in that century, improving at an even faster pace in the next 100 years. Economic growth thus eliminated mass poverty in what is today considered the developed world. Taking the long view, growth has also reduced poverty in other parts of the world: in 1820, about 75 percent of humanity lived on less than a dollar per day; today about 20 percent live under that amount.


-This guy forgets that poverty is a relative measure, not an absolute one. It´s ridiculous to measure poverty today and in 1820´s by the same criteria.

Even a short-term view confirms that the recent acceleration of growth in many developing countries has reduced poverty, measured the same way. In the past 10 years, the percentage of poor people in the developing world fell from 29 to 24 percent. Despite that progress, however, the number of poor people has remained stubbornly high at around 1,200 million. And geographically, reductions in poverty have been uneven.


-Depends on the trigger you use to measure poverty. While people earning US$1/day has declined, if you use a cutpoint of US$2, then the absolute number has increased and the % is stable. There are also strong doubts about the accuracy of those PPP measurements. There is an article called "How not to count the poor". I will try to get it to you. And there is more. When you exclude China (125th in freedom....), the poverty has actually increased. See the homepage of World Bank to get your info.


This mixed performance has prompted many observers to ask what factors other than growth reduce poverty and if growth is enough to accomplish that goal. Market reforms themselves have been questioned as a way of helping the poor. After all, many developing countries have liberalized their economies to varying degrees in the past decade.
But it would be a colossal mistake to lose focus on market-based growth and concentrate instead on redistribution or traditional poverty reduction programs that have done little by comparison to relieve poverty. Keeping the right focus is important for three reasons -- there is, in fact, a strong relationship between growth and poverty reduction, economic freedom causes growth, and most developing countries can still do much more in the way of policies and institutional reforms to help the poor.


-This guy has discovered the powder...it´s obvious that high growth rates
decrease poverty (althought high growth rates PLUS reduction of unequalities decrease poverty much more, this is simply mathematics). What is not proven is the relation between economic freedom (which, btw, is not easy to be measured) and economic growth.


That relationship explains why some countries and regions have done better than others. "Between 1987 and 1998, there was only one region of the world that saw a dramatic fall in both the number of people and the proportion of the population living on less than a dollar a day. That region was East Asia," observes economist Martin Wolf. "But this was also the only region to see consistent and rapid growth in real incomes per head."
High growth allowed East Asia to reduce the share of its poor during this period from 26 to 15 percent and the number of poor from 417 million to 278 million people. With annual growth rates of nearly 9 percent since 1979, when it began introducing market reforms, China alone has pulled more than 100 million people out of poverty.


-Another interesting point is to use income poverty as the only measurement of poverty. You must notice that, even if your income increase, you may actually become poorer if you start to pay for healthcare, education and other services. The poverty reduction in China is very real, but when you look to these variables, it might be less than anticipated. The healthcare system in the countryside collapsed with decollectivization, and some are reporting an increase in infant mortality rates there. Also the increasing unequalities in China decrease the potential for poverty reduction, in other words, the reduction is relatively modest, compared with the magnitude of economic growth.



The West's escape from poverty did not occur by chance. Sustained growth over long periods of time took place in an environment that generally encouraged free enterprise and the protection of private property.


-Imperialism had nothing with this :D


Today, developing countries have an advantage. By adopting liberal economic policies, poor countries can achieve within one generation the kind of economic progress that it took rich countries 100 years to achieve. High growth is possible because poor countries will be catching up to rich countries, rather than forging a new path. Studies by both the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund confirm that countries such as China and others that have chosen to open their economies are indeed converging with the industrialized world.


-Actually the "opening" of China and India had been very selective. While China is an agressive exporter, it keeps it internal market heavily protected. The very data of Heritage foundation fails to show a clear correlation between freedom and growth, althought IT SHOWS a clear correlation between merchantilism and growth.

The most comprehensive empirical study on the relationship between economic policies and prosperity is the Fraser Institute's "Economic Freedom of the World" annual report. It looks at more than 20 components of economic freedom, ranging from size of government to monetary and trade policy, in 123 countries over a 25-year period. The study finds a strong relationship between economic freedom and prosperity. Divided by quintiles, the freest economies have an average per capita income of $19,800 compared with $2,210 in the least free quintile. Freer economies also grow faster than less free economies. Per capita growth in the 1990s was 2.27 percent in the most free quintile, while it was -1.45 percent in the least free countries.


-And what about the intermediate quintiles? Merchantilist countries are probably include among them.


Globalization can be seen most clearly in the quickening pace and scope of international commerce. Global exports as a share of global domestic product have increased from 14 percent in 1970 to 24 percent today,2 and the growth of trade has consistently outpaced growth in global output.


-However, overall growth since 1970 has been clearly slower than in 195-70.


In contrast to those failed policies, certain countries have managed to dramatically improve their living standards by deregulating their domestic economies and opening up to global markets. The Four Tigers of East Asia--Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, and South Korea--are the most prominent examples. From typical Third World poverty in the 1950s, each has achieved a standard of living today equivalent to that of industrialized nations, with per-capita incomes in Hong Kong and Singapore rivaling those of the wealthiest Western nations.


-Right, but...
1-People forget that Hong Kong and Singapore are actually city states, so their model of development probably is not useful for bigger nations.
2-South Korea hardly can be considered a "free market" country. Actually that country have an intermediate to high level of state intervention, with restrictions on foreign investment, state ownership of banks (until mid 80´s), protectionism, state owned enterprises and five years plans for much of it history of economic development. The recent opening of that economic actually resulted in decreasing growth rates. To some extent, this is valid for Taiwan too (which, btw, received more external aid from US than Africa as a whole, which was useful to jumpstart their gowth)


In 1998, $ 166 billion in foreign direct investment flowed from the advanced economies to the less developed. A poor country that closes its door or fails to maintain sound domestic policies will forfeit the immense benefits this capital can bring.


-Brazil itself, received US$30billions and had 0,4% growth. Two years before, Indonesia received that amount and its economy collapsed by 1997. I see no clear relation between foreign investment and economic growth (btw, South Korea and Taiwan were relatively closed for foreign growth)



To fit into the Golden Straitjacket a country must either adopt, or be seen as moving toward, the following golden rules: making the private sector the primary engine of its economic growth, maintaining a low rate of inflation and price stability, shrinking the size of its state bureaucracy, maintaining as close to a balanced budget as possible, if not a surplus; eliminating and lowering tariffs on imported goods, removing restrictions on foreign investment, getting rid of quotas and domestic monopolies, increasing exports, privatizing state-owned industries and utilities, deregulating capital markets, making its currency convertible, opening its industries, stock, and bond markets to direct foreign ownership and investment, deregulating its economy to promote as much domestic competition as possible, eliminating government corruption, subsidies and kickbacks as much as possible, opening its banking and telecommunications systems to private ownership and competition, and allowing its citizens to choose from an array of competing pension options and foreign-run pension and mutual funds.7
While globalization may confront government officials with more difficult choices, the result for their citizens is greater individual freedom. In this sense, globalization acts as a check on governmental power, making it more difficult for governments to abuse the freedom and property of their citizens.


-These policies had been resulting in sucessive failures since 1997, if you didn´t notice yet....

Any casual survey of the world today will confirm that nations relatively open to trade tend to be more prosperous than nations that are relatively closed. The wealthiest nations and regions of the world- -western Europe, the United States, Canada, Japan, Hong Kong, Taiwan, South Korea, Singapore--are all trade-orientated. Their producers, with a few notable exceptions, must compete against other multinational producers in the global marketplace. In contrast, the poorest regions of the world--the Indian subcontinent and sub-Saharan Africa--remain (despite recent, halting reforms) the least friendly to foreign trade. And those countries that have moved decisively toward openness--Chile, China, and Poland, among others--have reaped real (and, in the case of China, spectacular) gains in living standards. [/quoted]

-Is US trade oriented? Actually the exports of that country account for only 10% of GNP, while imports are close to 15%. That is the most closed of developed countries. However this guy is 50% right. Autarky don´t work. What he misses is that free trade also don´t work. With the exception of Hong Kong and Singapore (whose particular situation I´ve already mentioned), those other countries protect their internal markets while press the others to open theirs. It´s a game of power, and not a fair game.

Systematic studies confirm a strong link between openness and economic growth.8 A study of 117 countries by Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Warner found that open economies grew much faster than closed economies. Specifically, the authors found that the developing countries that maintained open economies throughout the 1970s and '80s grew at an average annual rate of 4.5 percent, compared with an average growth rate of 0.7 percent for closed economies. As a result, the open developing economies tended to converge toward the slower-growing rich economies, while relatively closed economies did not converge.9


-Will look to that study.



Globally, the number of people living in absolute poverty has declined in the 1990s to an estimated 1.2 billion in 1998.14


-Only if you use the US$1 cutpoint



The United States itself is a classic example of the benign effect of trade and growth on the environment. It has simultaneously one of the most open economies and one of the cleanest environments in the world.


-And here we reach the world of fantasies. The US isn´t neither one nor another. It´s a relatively closed country as far as trade/GNP ratios are of concern and , in a per capita basis, it is one of the biggest carbon dioxide emissors of the world.
By Gothmog
#26866
Sorry, but I was browsing the Fraser Institute Website, and I simply cannot take them seriously. Please, explain me how a country like Austria, who had more than 50% of its economy nationalized until early 90´s, could be 17th in the rank of economic freedom?????
By Gothmog
#26868
Ahahahahahaha......and that is excellent. Communist Bulgaria was a country with relatively high economic freedom by 1985 :D
Rank=46th
Oooops, the degree of economic freedom in Bulgaria has actually DECLINED after 1990. Rank in 2000 is 101th. With those weird methodologies those guys can reach ANY conclusion they want.....
By Gothmog
#26872
Oops....and there is more to laugh. China seems not to be restoring capitalism....since 1985, its position in the rank of economic freedom has been steadily worsening(??), while absolute index is stagnated. I´m confused....
By Gothmog
#26874
Romania, under Ceuacesu had higher economic freedom index and nowadays....long live to Ceuacescu, that great liberal!!!
By Gothmog
#26877
More seriously, what seems to apply to those guys is that they place high levels of economic freedom where we have a stable order (that´s why socialist countries in mid 80´s had intermediate levels of freedom, instead of low levels). From my point this calculation method, like that from the Heritage foundation, is deeply biased, because "freedom" and "order" are not the same. And again they consider variables that are surrogate for poor performance as being equal to "freedom".
By econotarian
#30307
There is a reason why developing countries need trade to grow, the reason is comparative advantage.

If Alice can make 3 pens per hour or 1 pencil per hour, and Bob can make 1 pen per hour or 2 pencils per hour, if you put them both to work for two hours, what should they make?

Anti-globalists who support self-sufficiency believe that Alice and Bob should both make their own pencils and pens. In two hours, Alice makes herself 3 pens and then 1 pencil, and Bob makes himself 1 pen and 2 pencils, for a total of 4 pens and 3 pencils between them.

Free traders will put Alice to work only making pens for two hours, and Bob to work only making pencils for two hours. Alice will make 6 pens, and Bob will make 4 pencils, for a total of 6 pens and 4 pencils between them. That sure is better than just 4 pens and 3 pencils.

When agents produce the goods that they are best at producing, the global result is higher production. This is a mathematical fact.

The economic theory is that if developing countries can produce goods for lower costs than developed countries, they will produce more than if they tried to produce goods that developed countries can produce for lower costs.

The economic reality is that almost all developing countries that have experienced rapid economic growth did so along with the rapid expansion of trade (see http://www.econotarian.org/1055006499/index_html). This is probably due to comparative advantage.
By Gothmog
#30327
econotarian wrote:
The economic reality is that almost all developing countries that have experienced rapid economic growth did so along with the rapid expansion of trade (see http://www.econotarian.org/1055006499/index_html). This is probably due to comparative advantage.



USA has achieved superpower status largely by producing for the internal demand. By 1914 the USA was already the biggest economy in the world, but exports was about 6% of GDP while imports were ridiculous 3% of GDP (Rise and Fall of Great Powers). The very impressive Brazilian growth from 1920-80 (Brazil was one of the top economic performers of last century, with a annual per capita GDP growth of 2,5%) was also largely due to production for internal market-our economy was essentially stagnated when we relied on our "comparative advantages" on agricultural commodities. Countries who had impressive growth related to trade were those who protected their internal markets while focusing on exports (South Korea, Taiwan, China, Japan). Those who followed free trade policies had usually worse performances, unless they were city states (Singapore and Hong Kong).
Russia-Ukraine War 2022

It seems a critical moment in the conflict just ha[…]

The Crimean Tatar people's steadfast struggle agai[…]

NOVA SCOTIA (New Scotland, 18th Century) No fu[…]

If people have that impression then they're just […]